Political economy of China and US value chains in Latin America

  • Alberto J. Lebrón Veiga Institute of International Polítical Economy – Peking University
Keywords: Trade in Value Added (TiVA), US-China strategic competition, international production, Belt and Road Initiative, BRI

Abstract

In this paper, I aim to provide empirical evidence about how an efficient integration into global value chains can promote economic growth through industrial upgrading and prevention of external imbalances in Latin America (LATAM). I define US-China political economics in this region for the period from 1998 to 2015. The research uses TiVA raw data that I obtained from the UNCTAD-EORA database for the US, China, and nine major economies in LATAM.   The development of global value chains has brought unprecedented alternatives for commercial alliances and industrial strategies to developing countries. An effective integration of LATAM onto global value chains through forward linkages or increases in indirect value added (DVX) can strengthen both their industrial development and manufacturing industries to achieve the macroeconomic goal of long-term economic growth. China as the world’s fastest growing economy when trade is measured by the value added has stimulated forward linkages and economic development throughout several developing countries within the ASEAN+3, EU -13, and LATAM since 1998. However, strategic competition with the US has prevented China from further expanding its value chain to LATAM. Therefore, the whole region endures a peripherical position in relation to global value chains, as it is still too reliant on lower value-added investments in extractive industries. Yet strengthening TiVA exchanges with China, along with the US, is critical to broadening the alternatives for a sound and sustainable economic development in LATAM.

Downloads

View per year:  
Download data is not yet available.

References

Baldwin R. and Lopez-Gonzalez, J. Supply Chain Trade: A portrait of Global Patterns and Several Testable Hypotheses. 2015. The World Economy, 2015, p. 1691 (1682-1721).
Beverelli, C. et al. Domestic value chains as stepping stones to global value chain integration. The World Economy 42:5, 2019, pp. 1467-1494.
Callahan, W. China’ s Belt and Road Initiative and the New Eurasian Order. Norwegian Institute for International Affairs, 2016, p.3 (1-4)
Carluccio, J. et al. Trade, Wages and Collective Bargaining: Evidence from France. The Economic Journal 125:584, 2015, p. 815.
Dauth, W. et al. The Rise of the East and the Far East: German Labor Markets and Trade Integration. Journal of the European Economic Association 12:6, 2014, pp. 1643-1675.
Donoso, V. et al. Do Differences in the Exposure to Chinese Imports Lead to Differences in Local Labour Market Outcomes? An Analysis for Spanish Provinces. Regional Studies 49:10, 2015, p. 1748.
Feenstra, R. Integration of Trade and Desintegration of Production in the Global Economy. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Autumn, 1998, pp. 34 (31-50).
冯宗宪。中国向欧亚大陆延伸的战略动脉。人民论坛学术前沿,2014,(4):第80页。
Grereffi, G. et al. The Governance of Global Value Chains, Review of International Political Economy, 2005, Vol. 12, No. 1, p. 97.
Gereffi G. and Fernandez-Stark K. Global Value Chain Analysis: A Primer. Center on Globalization, Governance & Competitiveness (CGGC), Duke University, North Carolina, USA, 2011, p. 33.
Greenaway, D. et al. Trade Liberalization and Growth in Developing Countries. Journal of Developments Economics, Vol. 67 (2002), p. 237.
Grossman, G. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring. American Economic Review, 98(5), 2008, pp.1978-97.
Jacobson et al. Earnings Losses of Displaced Workers. American Economic Review, 1993, 83 (4), pp. 685-709.
Hagemejer, J. and Muagk, J. Export-led Growth and its Determinants: Evidence from CEEC Countries, doi: 10.1111/twec.12790, 2019, p. 19.
Inomata S. 全球价值链分析框架:综述,《全球价值链发展报告》,社会科学文献出版社,2017年,第22页。
Iodice, I. and Tomasi, C. Skill upgrading and wage gap: a decomposition analysis for Italian manufacturing firms. Economia Politica 33:2, 2016, p. 213.
Krasner, S. State Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. World Politics 28(3), 1976, p. 319.
Krugman, P. Does Third World Growth Hurt First World Prosperity? Harvard Business Review, 1996, 72, p. 115.
Kwok, T.S. International trade and the division of labor. Review of International Economics 26:2, 2018, p. 335 (322-338).
Lu, Y. et al. Does global value chain engagement improve firms' wages: Evidence from China. The World Economy 42:10, 2019, p. 3079.
Mann, M. Has Globalization Ended the Rise and Rise of the Nation-State? Review of International Political Economy, 4(3) Autumn: 1997, pp. 472–96.
Montalbano, P. et al. Opening and linking up: firms, GVCs, and productivity in Latin America. Small Business Economics 50:4, 2018, p. 918.
Naveed, A. and Ghulam, Shabbir. Trade Openness, FDI and Economic Growth: A Panel Study. Pakistan Economic and Social Review, Vol. 44, No. 1, 2006, p. 151.
Neal, D. Industry-specific Human Capital: Evidence from Displaced Workers. Journal of Labor Economics, 1995, 13(4), pp. 653-677.
Parent, D. Industry-specific Capital and the Wage Profile: Evidence from the NLSY and the PSID, Journal of Labor Economics, 2000, 18 (2), pp. 306-323.
Shimbov, B. et al. Export Structure Upgrading and Economic Growth in the Western Balkan Countries. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 55:10, 2019, pp. 2296-98.
Silva, M. Machinery production networks in Latin America: a quantity and quality analysis. Latin American Economic Review 26:1. 2017, p.4.
Stollinger, R. Structural Change and Global Value Chains in the EU, Empirica, 43, 2016, p. 803.
Tajoli, L. and Felice, G. Global Value Chains Participation and Knowledge Spillovers in Developed and Developing Countries: An Empirical Investigation. The European Journal of Development Research 30:3, 2018, p. 519.
Tang, X. How ‘Little’ Outsourcing Creates A Large Skill Premium: A Model of North-to-South Manufacturing Outsourcing. Pacific Economic Review 17:5, 2012, p. 646. (635-659).
Topel, R. Specific Capital, Mobility and Wages: Wages rise with Job Seniority. Journal of Political Economy, 1991, 99 (1), pp. 145-176.
Utar, H. When the Floodgates Open: “Northern” Firms' Response to Removal of Trade Quotas on Chinese Goods. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 6:4, 2014, pp. 226-250.
Vrh, N. The convergence in domestic value-added of exports in the EU. Post-Communist Economies 29:3, 2017, pp. 424
Wang Z. and Zeng J, From Economic Cooperation to Strategic Competition: Understanding the US-China Trade Disputes through the Transformed Relations. Journal of Chinese Political Science, 25, 2020, p.p. 49-69.
王跃生和陶涛。《世界经济结构、全球经济 “双循环” 与中国经济转型》,《新视野》2014 年第 1 期。第55页。
Xing, Y. Processing trade, exchange rates and China's bilateral trade balances. 2012. Journal of Asian Economics 23:5, pp. 540-547.
Xing, Y. Factoryless Manufacturers and International Trade in the Age of Global Value Chains. 2021. GRIPS, Tokio, Japan.
邢予青和Detert, N. 国际分工与美中贸易逆差: 以i-Phone为例。金融研究,2011年,第198-206页。
Yeung, H. Regional development in the global economy: A dynamic perspective of strategic coupling in global production networks. Regional Science Policy & Practice 7:1, 2015, p. 6.
Yi, K. Can Vertical Specialization Explain the Growth of World Trade? Journal of Political Economy, 111(1): 2003, p. 91.
Yu, C. and Luo, Z. What are China's real gains within global value chains? Measuring domestic value added in China's exports of manufactures. China Economic Review 47, 2018, pp. 263-273.
Published
2023-01-05
How to Cite
Lebrón Veiga, A. J. (2023). Political economy of China and US value chains in Latin America. Journal of Business, Universidad Del Pacífico (Lima, Peru), 14(1), 87-107. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.21678/jb.2022.2031
Section
Articles